Human Capital
"The Role of Option Value in College Decisions," Economic Brief No. 16-04, April 2016.
"On the Distribution of College Dropouts: Wealth and Uninsurable Idiosyncratic Risk," Working Paper No. 15-15, November 2015.
"The Prevalence of Apprenticeships in Germany and the United States," Economic Brief No. 14-08, August 2014.
"Implications of Risks and Rewards in College Decisions," Economic Brief No. 13-06, June 2013.
College education has also risen significantly in recent decades. According to a 2016 paper by Camille Ryan and Kurt Bauman of the U.S. Census Bureau, a little more than 15 percent of Americans aged 25 to 29 had completed a four-year college degree in 1970, compared to 36 percent in 2015. Human capital theory holds that this trend has been driven in large part by the expected payoff; as with all investments, people accumulate more human capital when they expect the returns to be higher.
The returns to college are high and growing: Students who complete a four-year undergraduate degree receive, on average, a large wage premium over those who do not, a premium that has been rising since the late 1970s. One analysis has concluded that workers with undergraduate degrees (and who stopped there) received 1.75 times the wages of a high-school-only graduate in 2005, up from 1.4 times in 1980 — a trend that economists believe is a reflection of changes in the demand for skills in a more high-tech-based economy. (Of course, the wage premium depends on the student's field, among other factors.)
Moreover, graduate and professional education is of growing importance to earnings: According to a 2012 study by Jonathan James, then of the Cleveland Fed, the college premium is increasingly conditional on the student also completing a graduate or professional degree. All of the growth in the college wage premium since the 2000s, James found, has gone to holders of advanced degrees.
But although higher education is a lucrative human-capital investment for many, it can also be a risky one. Around half of students who enter college end up leaving without a degree — perhaps as a result of inadequate preparation before college or personal difficulties — and the return to attending college without actually earning a degree is generally low. Thus, these students face a depressing combination of debt (or lost savings) and low earnings. Richmond Fed research director Kartik Athreya and co-author Janice Eberly of Northwestern University have argued that such risks have slowed the growth of college-going. (See also the Richmond Fed's 2017 Annual Report essay, "Falling Short: Why Isn't the U.S. Producing More College Graduates?")
Young people who eschew the four-year college route will often still make investments in their human capital — through a two-year associate's degree, on-the-job experience, or formal job-based training programs such as apprenticeships. (See "Learning in the Fast Lane," Econ Focus, Fourth Quarter 2017.)
In Schultz's 1960 remarks on human capital, he noted one of its unusual attributes: Unlike typical investments in physical capital, investments in human capital — especially formal education — are often a consumption good as well, which has the effect of "improving the taste and quality of consumption of students throughout the rest of their lives." This, he said, may increase the true rate of return to education far above its observed financial rate of return. So take heart when your next student-loan payment is debited from your bank account.
Receive an email notification when Econ Focus is posted online.